WEBVTT 00:00:00.270 --> 00:00:01.920 - [Instructor] What we're gonna do in this video 00:00:01.920 --> 00:00:04.260 is talk about some interesting things 00:00:04.260 --> 00:00:07.380 that have happened since 2008, and in particular, 00:00:07.380 --> 00:00:12.060 we're gonna talk about what an ample reserves regime is, 00:00:12.060 --> 00:00:15.600 but even more importantly, what its actual implications are 00:00:15.600 --> 00:00:18.300 and how you can analyze it with a graph like this. 00:00:18.300 --> 00:00:20.820 So let's just make sure we have our bearings first. 00:00:20.820 --> 00:00:25.820 So the horizontal axis right over here is reserve balances, 00:00:25.890 --> 00:00:29.910 and then the vertical axis here is interest rates. 00:00:29.910 --> 00:00:32.010 So for the first part of this discussion, 00:00:32.010 --> 00:00:35.640 let's ignore everything that we see in gray over here. 00:00:35.640 --> 00:00:36.720 That's what we're gonna talk about 00:00:36.720 --> 00:00:39.180 when we talk about the ample reserves regimes. 00:00:39.180 --> 00:00:43.110 Let's say we're talking about a period pre-2008. 00:00:43.110 --> 00:00:44.880 And in that situation, 00:00:44.880 --> 00:00:48.720 you could imagine the more reserve balances you have, 00:00:48.720 --> 00:00:52.350 the lower the demand is for reserve balances, 00:00:52.350 --> 00:00:54.960 because if more banks are sitting on reserves, 00:00:54.960 --> 00:00:58.950 well, then they don't need to go into the market 00:00:58.950 --> 00:01:01.140 and borrow reserves as much. 00:01:01.140 --> 00:01:03.450 And so what you would naturally expect 00:01:03.450 --> 00:01:08.130 is as reserve balances increase, demand goes down 00:01:08.130 --> 00:01:11.580 and of course, the actual interest 00:01:11.580 --> 00:01:15.510 that people would need to pay in order to get reserves 00:01:15.510 --> 00:01:17.310 if they're running low would go down. 00:01:17.310 --> 00:01:20.100 So, for example, let's ignore this red line here. 00:01:20.100 --> 00:01:25.100 Let's imagine a pre-2008 scenario where the actual reserves, 00:01:25.770 --> 00:01:28.440 the supply of reserves looks like this. 00:01:28.440 --> 00:01:31.260 And of course, the Federal Reserve can determine this 00:01:31.260 --> 00:01:34.320 by printing money, increasing its balance sheet 00:01:34.320 --> 00:01:35.700 or contracting its balance sheet. 00:01:35.700 --> 00:01:39.000 They can do that as they see fit. 00:01:39.000 --> 00:01:40.680 So in this situation right over here, 00:01:40.680 --> 00:01:43.710 these are the total reserves that are in the system 00:01:43.710 --> 00:01:45.660 that the Federal Reserve can decide. 00:01:45.660 --> 00:01:50.660 And you have now a market rate for overnight reserves. 00:01:51.270 --> 00:01:52.710 So if a bank is running low, 00:01:52.710 --> 00:01:54.120 let's say they had a lot of withdrawals, 00:01:54.120 --> 00:01:56.730 they need to meet their reserve requirements back then, 00:01:56.730 --> 00:01:59.910 well, then they would go into the, quote, money market 00:01:59.910 --> 00:02:03.090 and they would borrow some of that money from a bank 00:02:03.090 --> 00:02:05.640 that has excess reserves. 00:02:05.640 --> 00:02:06.810 Now, you might be wondering, 00:02:06.810 --> 00:02:09.570 why does this curve, this blue curve flatten out 00:02:09.570 --> 00:02:11.640 as you go further and further to the left? 00:02:11.640 --> 00:02:13.650 Why doesn't it do something like this? 00:02:13.650 --> 00:02:16.200 If the reserve balances are lower, and lower, lower, 00:02:16.200 --> 00:02:17.670 you'd think people would charge higher 00:02:17.670 --> 00:02:21.840 and higher interest rates to land reserves overnight. 00:02:21.840 --> 00:02:25.350 Well, what puts a cap on this is the discount window. 00:02:25.350 --> 00:02:27.420 This primary credit rate, this is the rate 00:02:27.420 --> 00:02:30.240 that a bank in good standing, a strong bank, 00:02:30.240 --> 00:02:31.680 you also have a secondary credit rate 00:02:31.680 --> 00:02:34.140 for slightly weaker bank, that would be a higher rate, 00:02:34.140 --> 00:02:35.220 but this is essentially 00:02:35.220 --> 00:02:37.440 what banks can go to the Federal Reserve 00:02:37.440 --> 00:02:39.690 and borrow directly from the Federal Reserve 00:02:39.690 --> 00:02:41.550 at the discount window. 00:02:41.550 --> 00:02:44.250 So that discount window rate right over here, 00:02:44.250 --> 00:02:47.730 that essentially puts a cap on the overnight borrowing rate, 00:02:47.730 --> 00:02:50.790 a cap on the rate that a bank would have to pay 00:02:50.790 --> 00:02:52.380 in order to borrow reserves. 00:02:52.380 --> 00:02:54.540 And so that's why you see the curve 00:02:54.540 --> 00:02:57.360 essentially gets limited by that. 00:02:57.360 --> 00:03:01.470 But now let's think about what happened in 2008, 00:03:01.470 --> 00:03:04.980 and to understand that, I always get a kick 00:03:04.980 --> 00:03:07.620 out of looking at the total assets of the Federal Reserve. 00:03:07.620 --> 00:03:10.350 This is essentially the Federal Reserve's balance sheet. 00:03:10.350 --> 00:03:12.600 You can view this as how much base money 00:03:12.600 --> 00:03:14.430 they have put into circulation. 00:03:14.430 --> 00:03:16.350 And I know these numbers are hard to read, 00:03:16.350 --> 00:03:18.150 so let me write it down for you. 00:03:18.150 --> 00:03:21.623 Out here, that is 2008, 2008. 00:03:23.790 --> 00:03:26.280 And the rightmost point, 00:03:26.280 --> 00:03:28.320 we are about three fourths of the way 00:03:28.320 --> 00:03:33.120 through 2023 over here. 00:03:33.120 --> 00:03:35.906 Now, you see something interesting happening 00:03:35.906 --> 00:03:40.906 essentially a little bit midway through 2008. 00:03:41.130 --> 00:03:43.710 The balance sheet increases significantly. 00:03:43.710 --> 00:03:46.950 We go from roughly 1 trillion of base money 00:03:46.950 --> 00:03:50.520 to $2 trillion of base money. 00:03:50.520 --> 00:03:52.770 So essentially what the Federal Reserve was doing, 00:03:52.770 --> 00:03:54.750 they were taking this vertical line 00:03:54.750 --> 00:03:58.020 and they were pushing it far to the right over here. 00:03:58.020 --> 00:04:00.900 Now, you might think historically why were they doing that. 00:04:00.900 --> 00:04:03.960 Well, some of you might remember, we had banks failing. 00:04:03.960 --> 00:04:05.700 It had a financial crisis. 00:04:05.700 --> 00:04:08.790 They wanted to shore up not just the banking system, 00:04:08.790 --> 00:04:10.500 but also the economy. 00:04:10.500 --> 00:04:13.650 So the Federal Reserve just started printing money, 00:04:13.650 --> 00:04:16.770 and it put us into a new territory, 00:04:16.770 --> 00:04:19.710 a territory of ample reserves. 00:04:19.710 --> 00:04:22.830 That's why it's called an ample reserves regime. 00:04:22.830 --> 00:04:24.810 Now, there's an interesting question, though. 00:04:24.810 --> 00:04:27.120 If you go to a situation of ample reserves, 00:04:27.120 --> 00:04:28.530 and that's essentially the situation 00:04:28.530 --> 00:04:32.550 that we could imagine right over here, 00:04:32.550 --> 00:04:35.430 well, if you just had your traditional demand curve here, 00:04:35.430 --> 00:04:38.370 this curve would've just kept going down and down and down. 00:04:38.370 --> 00:04:40.920 And essentially there's so much reserves in the system 00:04:40.920 --> 00:04:42.660 that the demand would go so low 00:04:42.660 --> 00:04:44.340 that if a bank had access reserves, 00:04:44.340 --> 00:04:46.530 it would pretty much get little to no interest 00:04:46.530 --> 00:04:48.150 on those reserves. 00:04:48.150 --> 00:04:50.640 Now, that's a tough situation in and of itself 00:04:50.640 --> 00:04:53.220 because some of those banks needed that interest on reserves 00:04:53.220 --> 00:04:55.350 because, once again, they were all in a tough situation. 00:04:55.350 --> 00:04:56.820 And also, you want a situation 00:04:56.820 --> 00:04:59.220 where banks could probably attract some depositors 00:04:59.220 --> 00:05:01.260 by hopefully giving some interest 00:05:01.260 --> 00:05:03.150 to the depositors themselves. 00:05:03.150 --> 00:05:05.730 That also would strengthen the banking system. 00:05:05.730 --> 00:05:08.940 So that's when in this ample reserves regime, 00:05:08.940 --> 00:05:11.100 the Federal Reserve did something else. 00:05:11.100 --> 00:05:13.740 They said, "Okay, banks, it is no longer the case 00:05:13.740 --> 00:05:15.510 that the only way that you could get interest 00:05:15.510 --> 00:05:18.420 on your reserves is by lending it to other banks. 00:05:18.420 --> 00:05:21.090 We're going to allow you to take those reserves 00:05:21.090 --> 00:05:24.870 and deposit them with us, with the Federal Reserve, 00:05:24.870 --> 00:05:28.200 and we will give you interest on those reserves." 00:05:28.200 --> 00:05:31.890 That's what this IOR is, interest on reserves. 00:05:31.890 --> 00:05:35.280 And so if you are a banking institution, 00:05:35.280 --> 00:05:39.360 this essentially set up a floor on the interest 00:05:39.360 --> 00:05:41.940 that you would get on your reserves. 00:05:41.940 --> 00:05:44.460 Now, the question you might be wondering is, 00:05:44.460 --> 00:05:45.930 why doesn't this blue line then 00:05:45.930 --> 00:05:48.210 just flatten out right over there? 00:05:48.210 --> 00:05:50.580 And in some more simplified diagrams, 00:05:50.580 --> 00:05:52.530 you will actually see that. 00:05:52.530 --> 00:05:56.010 But it turns out that banks are not the only participants 00:05:56.010 --> 00:05:57.270 in the money market. 00:05:57.270 --> 00:05:58.410 You have other people 00:05:58.410 --> 00:06:00.780 who are potentially lending reserves to banks, 00:06:00.780 --> 00:06:02.520 and they don't have access 00:06:02.520 --> 00:06:05.190 to depositing their reserves with the Federal Reserve. 00:06:05.190 --> 00:06:07.230 So that's not a floor on them. 00:06:07.230 --> 00:06:09.300 The Federal Reserve introduced another rate. 00:06:09.300 --> 00:06:12.330 I won't go into the details of what on RRP stands for. 00:06:12.330 --> 00:06:14.490 These essentially repurchase agreements. 00:06:14.490 --> 00:06:17.190 This is essentially the Federal Reserve giving interest 00:06:17.190 --> 00:06:21.840 to non-banking institutions on reserves that they place 00:06:21.840 --> 00:06:23.790 with the actual Federal Reserve. 00:06:23.790 --> 00:06:27.960 So this places a hard floor, 'cause even those folks, 00:06:27.960 --> 00:06:29.460 they would never wanna lend below this 00:06:29.460 --> 00:06:31.230 because they could get that much interest 00:06:31.230 --> 00:06:33.330 with the Federal Reserve. 00:06:33.330 --> 00:06:35.520 Now, the next question you might be wondering is, 00:06:35.520 --> 00:06:39.990 all right, if we are out here in this ample reserves regime, 00:06:39.990 --> 00:06:43.260 traditionally the Federal Reserve could change 00:06:43.260 --> 00:06:45.570 the federal funds rate, the target rate 00:06:45.570 --> 00:06:48.540 by moving this red line to the left and the right. 00:06:48.540 --> 00:06:51.180 If you're in a non-ample reserves regime, 00:06:51.180 --> 00:06:54.690 if you move this red line to the left, 00:06:54.690 --> 00:06:55.920 well, what's gonna happen? 00:06:55.920 --> 00:06:57.960 You're going to essentially increase 00:06:57.960 --> 00:06:59.910 the overnight borrowing rate, 00:06:59.910 --> 00:07:02.400 and that would constrict the economy. 00:07:02.400 --> 00:07:03.960 And if you move it to the right, 00:07:03.960 --> 00:07:06.930 you're going to decrease the overnight borrowing rate, 00:07:06.930 --> 00:07:09.270 and that would stimulate the economy. 00:07:09.270 --> 00:07:10.920 If you're out here on the right side, 00:07:10.920 --> 00:07:14.220 if you move this vertical red line to the right or the left, 00:07:14.220 --> 00:07:16.680 it's not going to change the overnight borrowing rate 00:07:16.680 --> 00:07:18.120 because you're essentially going to be hugging 00:07:18.120 --> 00:07:20.670 this pretty flat blue line. 00:07:20.670 --> 00:07:23.670 And things have gotten even more ample since 2008. 00:07:23.670 --> 00:07:26.250 We went from roughly 1 trillion to 2 trillion, 00:07:26.250 --> 00:07:30.240 and then out here we are getting, approaching 8, 9 trillion. 00:07:30.240 --> 00:07:32.400 And you might say, "Well, what happened right over here?" 00:07:32.400 --> 00:07:35.430 Well, that was the COVID pandemic, where, once again, 00:07:35.430 --> 00:07:38.160 the Federal Reserve really wanted to stimulate the economy, 00:07:38.160 --> 00:07:41.580 and they did that by printing a ton of money. 00:07:41.580 --> 00:07:45.180 So in the scenario that we've been in for a while now, 00:07:45.180 --> 00:07:48.090 we are deep into an ample reserves regime. 00:07:48.090 --> 00:07:50.070 If we were in ample reserves in 2008, 00:07:50.070 --> 00:07:53.970 we're that much further right now in the 2020s. 00:07:53.970 --> 00:07:55.380 So how does the Federal Reserve 00:07:55.380 --> 00:07:57.720 actually control interest rates now? 00:07:57.720 --> 00:08:00.750 Well, what they can do is they can control these floors, 00:08:00.750 --> 00:08:02.940 or you could say this floor right over here. 00:08:02.940 --> 00:08:05.670 If they want to increase interest rates, 00:08:05.670 --> 00:08:08.910 they just increase the interest on reserves they give. 00:08:08.910 --> 00:08:10.080 And if they do that, 00:08:10.080 --> 00:08:13.200 then the curve will look something like this, 00:08:13.200 --> 00:08:15.720 and then the overnight borrowing rate will be higher, 00:08:15.720 --> 00:08:18.030 and then, of course, that would be restrictive 00:08:18.030 --> 00:08:20.340 for the economy, and if they wanna loosen, 00:08:20.340 --> 00:08:24.123 they can likewise lower the interest on reserves.