< Return to Video

What Are Negative Externalities?

  • 0:00 - 0:02
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:04 - 0:07
    - [Tyler] Let's travel back
    to June 1924.
  • 0:07 - 0:10
    President Coolidge's son,
    Calvin Jr.
  • 0:10 - 0:13
    is outside the White House
    playing lawn tennis.
  • 0:13 - 0:14
    While playing,
  • 0:14 - 0:17
    he develops a blister
    on his right foot.
  • 0:19 - 0:20
    A week later,
  • 0:21 - 0:22
    Calvin Jr. is dead.
  • 0:24 - 0:27
    A simple staph infection
    developed from a blister
  • 0:27 - 0:28
    leading to sepsis.
  • 0:30 - 0:33
    Even though Calvin Jr.
    was the president's son,
  • 0:33 - 0:35
    there was no medicine to save him.
  • 0:36 - 0:38
    Deaths from infection
    were common at the time.
  • 0:39 - 0:42
    Even small wounds could become
    a life or death ordeal.
  • 0:43 - 0:44
    Just four years later,
  • 0:44 - 0:46
    penicillin was discovered --
  • 0:46 - 0:49
    a breakthrough that could
    have saved Calvin Jr.'s life.
  • 0:50 - 0:54
    This first antibiotic
    revolutionized medicine.
  • 0:54 - 0:58
    Once fatal, bacterial infections
    became easily curable.
  • 0:59 - 1:03
    But today, that miracle
    is under threat from superbugs --
  • 1:03 - 1:06
    bacteria resistant to antibiotics.
  • 1:07 - 1:08
    How did superbugs happen?
  • 1:09 - 1:11
    And what does this have to do
    with economics?
  • 1:12 - 1:14
    In the market for antibiotics,
  • 1:14 - 1:15
    we have buyers
  • 1:15 - 1:17
    -- represented
    by the demand curve --
  • 1:17 - 1:20
    and sellers -- represented
    by the supply curve.
  • 1:21 - 1:23
    A trade happens
    when the buyer values the good
  • 1:23 - 1:25
    more than the market price
  • 1:25 - 1:27
    and the seller values
    the market price
  • 1:27 - 1:28
    more than the good.
  • 1:29 - 1:31
    The buyer and the seller transact,
  • 1:31 - 1:32
    and both benefit.
  • 1:33 - 1:35
    All the buyers on this part
    of the demand curve
  • 1:35 - 1:38
    value the antibiotics
    more than the price,
  • 1:38 - 1:39
    and they buy them.
  • 1:40 - 1:43
    All the sellers on this part
    of the supply curve
  • 1:43 - 1:45
    can produce antibiotics for profit
  • 1:45 - 1:46
    and sell them.
  • 1:47 - 1:50
    When we say a market maximizes
    the gains from trade,
  • 1:51 - 1:54
    we're referring to every trade
    being mutually beneficial.
  • 1:55 - 1:58
    Consumer and producer surplus
    are maximized.
  • 1:59 - 2:01
    This is why economists
    like markets.
  • 2:02 - 2:03
    But now we have a problem:
  • 2:03 - 2:05
    those pesky superbugs.
  • 2:06 - 2:10
    We have to introduce
    a new entity into our analysis:
  • 2:10 - 2:11
    the bystanders.
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    Bystanders
    are neither buying nor selling,
  • 2:15 - 2:16
    but nonetheless, they're affected
  • 2:16 - 2:19
    by the purchase
    and use of antibiotics.
  • 2:20 - 2:23
    The economic concept
    of externalities
  • 2:23 - 2:26
    describes the effect
    of market trade on bystanders.
  • 2:26 - 2:28
    When bystanders bear a cost,
  • 2:28 - 2:30
    it's called a negative externality.
  • 2:30 - 2:32
    When bystanders receive a benefit,
  • 2:33 - 2:35
    that's called
    a positive externality.
  • 2:36 - 2:37
    Either way,
  • 2:37 - 2:40
    buyers and sellers do not
    typically consider externalities
  • 2:40 - 2:42
    on other people,
  • 2:42 - 2:44
    and that means
    the market equilibrium
  • 2:44 - 2:48
    will maximize the sum
    of producer and consumer surplus
  • 2:48 - 2:50
    but not bystander surplus.
  • 2:50 - 2:52
    And that's not good.
  • 2:53 - 2:57
    The use of antibiotics
    has a negative externality problem.
  • 2:57 - 2:58
    Why is that?
  • 2:59 - 3:02
    No antibiotic is 100% effective.
  • 3:03 - 3:06
    The antibiotic kills some bacteria,
  • 3:06 - 3:09
    but some stronger bacteria survive,
  • 3:09 - 3:11
    flourish, and reproduce,
  • 3:11 - 3:15
    eventually rendering
    the antibiotic ineffective.
  • 3:15 - 3:17
    We then develop a new antibiotic,
  • 3:18 - 3:19
    and the story repeats.
  • 3:20 - 3:22
    Play this evolutionary process out,
  • 3:22 - 3:24
    and you end up with superbugs
  • 3:24 - 3:27
    that are resistant
    to many of our antibiotics.
  • 3:28 - 3:29
    The fundamental problem
  • 3:29 - 3:33
    is that antibiotic users reap
    all the benefits of antibiotic use
  • 3:34 - 3:36
    without bearing all of the costs.
  • 3:36 - 3:40
    Each use of an antibiotic
    creates a small increase
  • 3:40 - 3:41
    in bacterial resistance.
  • 3:42 - 3:44
    We all suffer the consequences
  • 3:44 - 3:47
    of the resulting
    less effective antibiotics
  • 3:47 - 3:49
    every time that someone uses them.
  • 3:49 - 3:52
    Now, let's deploy supply and demand
  • 3:52 - 3:55
    to better visualize
    this externality problem.
  • 3:56 - 3:58
    Here's our standard diagram
  • 3:58 - 4:00
    with the quantity of antibiotics
  • 4:00 - 4:02
    on the horizontal axis.
  • 4:02 - 4:04
    On the vertical axis,
  • 4:04 - 4:06
    we're showing both prices and costs
  • 4:06 - 4:10
    so that we can illustrate both
    the price charged for antibiotics
  • 4:10 - 4:12
    and the costs to bystanders.
  • 4:12 - 4:15
    As usual, the equilibrium is found
  • 4:15 - 4:17
    where demand intersects supply.
  • 4:18 - 4:19
    Now, the key point
  • 4:19 - 4:21
    is that the supply curve is based
  • 4:21 - 4:23
    on what we'll call
    the "private cost" --
  • 4:23 - 4:26
    the cost of producing
    the antibiotic
  • 4:26 - 4:27
    paid by the supplier.
  • 4:28 - 4:30
    But we know there's another cost.
  • 4:30 - 4:33
    Every time an antibiotic
    is produced and consumed,
  • 4:33 - 4:36
    there's a cost of increased
    bacterial resistance.
  • 4:37 - 4:39
    We'll call that
    the "external cost."
  • 4:40 - 4:43
    Negative externality
    is just another way of saying
  • 4:43 - 4:46
    there's an external cost
    on bystanders.
  • 4:47 - 4:49
    Suppliers do not typically consider
  • 4:49 - 4:53
    the external costs
    of their production to bystanders,
  • 4:53 - 4:56
    so bystander costs
    are not reflected in the price.
  • 4:57 - 4:59
    We can add the external cost
  • 4:59 - 5:01
    to the private supply curve
  • 5:01 - 5:02
    to make a new curve:
  • 5:02 - 5:04
    the social cost curve.
  • 5:04 - 5:06
    The social cost
    is the cost to everyone,
  • 5:06 - 5:08
    including bystanders.
  • 5:09 - 5:12
    The vertical distance here
    is the external cost --
  • 5:12 - 5:13
    the cost to bystanders.
  • 5:14 - 5:17
    Now, let's evaluate
    both quantities.
  • 5:17 - 5:21
    The market equilibrium shows
    the quantity the market produces --
  • 5:21 - 5:25
    the quantity that maximizes
    producer and consumer surplus.
  • 5:26 - 5:29
    But we want to maximize
    social surplus,
  • 5:29 - 5:31
    which is the total
    net value created,
  • 5:31 - 5:34
    namely the sum of consumer surplus,
  • 5:34 - 5:37
    producer surplus,
    and bystander surplus.
  • 5:38 - 5:40
    Since we have large external costs,
  • 5:40 - 5:42
    we don't want to produce
  • 5:42 - 5:43
    at the market equilibrium.
  • 5:44 - 5:45
    We want to produce here,
  • 5:46 - 5:49
    where the social cost curve
    intersects the demand curve --
  • 5:49 - 5:52
    that's where social surplus
    is maximized.
  • 5:53 - 5:55
    You can see that
    the market equilibrium quantity
  • 5:55 - 5:58
    is higher than
    the socially efficient quantity.
  • 5:59 - 6:02
    This difference represents
    the overuse of antibiotics.
  • 6:03 - 6:05
    We can show this in another way.
  • 6:05 - 6:07
    Let's look at the value
  • 6:07 - 6:09
    of the last unit
    the market produces.
  • 6:10 - 6:12
    What's the value of that last unit?
  • 6:12 - 6:14
    The private value is given
  • 6:14 - 6:16
    by the height
    of the demand curve --
  • 6:16 - 6:18
    that's what consumers
    are willing to pay.
  • 6:19 - 6:21
    What's the cost of that last unit?
  • 6:22 - 6:23
    The private cost is given
  • 6:23 - 6:25
    by the private supply curve,
  • 6:25 - 6:27
    but the social cost is given
  • 6:27 - 6:30
    by the higher social cost curve.
  • 6:30 - 6:32
    We don't want
    to produce this last unit
  • 6:32 - 6:35
    because the social cost
    is greater than the value.
  • 6:36 - 6:39
    If we don't want
    to produce that last unit,
  • 6:39 - 6:41
    then we don't want
    to produce any of the units
  • 6:41 - 6:44
    where the social cost is going
    to be greater than the value.
  • 6:45 - 6:46
    In other words,
  • 6:46 - 6:48
    this area is a deadweight loss.
  • 6:49 - 6:51
    The social cost of these units
  • 6:51 - 6:53
    is greater than their value.
  • 6:53 - 6:55
    Producing these units means
  • 6:55 - 6:58
    society is worse off as a result.
  • 6:58 - 7:01
    And this represents
    the loss to society
  • 7:01 - 7:03
    from the overuse of antibiotics.
  • 7:04 - 7:06
    So what conclusions can we draw?
  • 7:07 - 7:09
    If every deployment
    of an antibiotic
  • 7:09 - 7:10
    had a high-value use
  • 7:10 - 7:12
    -- say, if it saved a life --
  • 7:12 - 7:15
    then the rise of superbugs
    would be unfortunate,
  • 7:15 - 7:17
    but not necessarily something
  • 7:17 - 7:19
    we could or should do
    something about.
  • 7:20 - 7:22
    But in fact, antibiotics
    are often deployed
  • 7:22 - 7:24
    in low-value uses.
  • 7:24 - 7:25
    For instance,
  • 7:25 - 7:27
    sometimes people take antibiotics
  • 7:27 - 7:29
    when they don't even need them.
  • 7:30 - 7:33
    The market price does not include
    the external costs,
  • 7:33 - 7:35
    namely the costs
    of bacterial resistance
  • 7:35 - 7:37
    on bystanders.
  • 7:37 - 7:39
    It's incentivizing consumption
  • 7:39 - 7:42
    where the social cost
    exceeds the value.
  • 7:43 - 7:45
    The market price
    of antibiotics is too low.
  • 7:46 - 7:49
    We would like to discourage
    these low-value uses
  • 7:49 - 7:50
    with a higher price.
  • 7:52 - 7:54
    Many people assume
    with a negative externality
  • 7:54 - 7:56
    that the optimal quantity is zero,
  • 7:57 - 7:59
    but that's almost never the case.
  • 7:59 - 8:00
    We still want the people
  • 8:00 - 8:02
    who highly value
    the good to buy it --
  • 8:03 - 8:04
    in this example, for instance,
  • 8:04 - 8:06
    someone with a dangerous infection.
  • 8:07 - 8:09
    We just don't want
    to produce and sell goods
  • 8:09 - 8:12
    whose value is less
    than the social cost.
  • 8:12 - 8:16
    Remember that a free market
    maximizes consumer surplus
  • 8:16 - 8:17
    plus producer surplus,
  • 8:17 - 8:19
    but it does not take into account
  • 8:19 - 8:21
    the costs or benefits
    to bystanders.
  • 8:22 - 8:23
    Ultimately, what we care about
  • 8:23 - 8:25
    is the total social surplus --
  • 8:25 - 8:27
    costs and benefits to consumers,
  • 8:27 - 8:30
    producers, and also to bystanders.
  • 8:30 - 8:32
    When external costs are large,
  • 8:32 - 8:35
    the market will not maximize
    social surplus.
  • 8:36 - 8:37
    Externalities,
  • 8:37 - 8:38
    whether negative or positive,
  • 8:38 - 8:41
    are useful tools
    for analyzing markets
  • 8:41 - 8:44
    and leading us
    toward a variety of solutions
  • 8:44 - 8:45
    to account for them.
  • 8:45 - 8:48
    We'll discuss those
    in other videos.
  • 8:49 - 8:51
    - [Narrator] If you're a teacher,
    you should check out
  • 8:51 - 8:53
    our Externalities
    and Public Goods Unit Plan
  • 8:53 - 8:55
    that incorporates this video.
  • 8:55 - 8:57
    If you're a learner,
    make sure this video sticks
  • 8:57 - 8:59
    by answering
    a few quick practice questions.
  • 8:59 - 9:02
    Or, if you're ready
    for more microeconomics,
  • 9:02 - 9:03
    click for the next video.
  • 9:03 - 9:05
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
What Are Negative Externalities?
ASR Confidence:
1.00
Description:

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Other videos
Duration:
09:09

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions