< Return to Video

Optimal point on budget line | Microeconomics | Khan Academy

  • 0:01 - 0:03
    So let's just review what
    we've seen with budget lines.
  • 0:03 - 0:06
    Let's say I'm
    making $20 a month.
  • 0:06 - 0:09
    So my income is $20 per month.
  • 0:09 - 0:10
    Let's say per month.
  • 0:12 - 0:18
    The price of chocolate
    is $1 per bar.
  • 0:18 - 0:24
    And the price of
    fruit is $2 per pound.
  • 0:24 - 0:25
    And we've already
    done this before,
  • 0:25 - 0:28
    but I'll just redraw
    a budget line.
  • 0:28 - 0:31
    So this axis, let's say this
    is the quantity of chocolate.
  • 0:31 - 0:33
    I could have picked
    it either way.
  • 0:33 - 0:36
    And that is the
    quantity of fruit.
  • 0:40 - 0:42
    If I spend all my
    money on chocolate,
  • 0:42 - 0:45
    I could buy 20 bars
    of chocolate a month.
  • 0:45 - 0:46
    So that is 20.
  • 0:46 - 0:47
    This is 10 right over here.
  • 0:47 - 0:50
    At these prices, if I
    spent all my money on fruit
  • 0:50 - 0:52
    I could buy 10 pounds per month.
  • 0:52 - 0:53
    So this is 10.
  • 0:53 - 0:55
    So that's 10 pounds per month.
  • 0:55 - 0:56
    That would be 20.
  • 0:56 - 0:58
    And so I have a budget
    line that looks like this.
  • 1:01 - 1:04
    And the equation of this budget
    line is going to be-- well,
  • 1:04 - 1:05
    I could write it like this.
  • 1:05 - 1:09
    My budget, 20, is going
    to be equal to the price
  • 1:09 - 1:13
    of chocolate, which is 1, times
    the quantity of chocolate.
  • 1:13 - 1:16
    So this is 1 times the
    quantity of chocolate,
  • 1:16 - 1:19
    plus the price of
    fruit, which is
  • 1:19 - 1:24
    2 times the quantity of fruit.
  • 1:24 - 1:25
    And if I want to
    write this explicitly
  • 1:25 - 1:27
    in terms of my
    quantity of chocolate,
  • 1:27 - 1:29
    since I put that
    on my vertical axis
  • 1:29 - 1:31
    and that tends to be
    the more dependent axis,
  • 1:31 - 1:34
    I can just subtract 2
    times the quantity of fruit
  • 1:34 - 1:34
    from both sides.
  • 1:34 - 1:36
    And I can flip them.
  • 1:36 - 1:38
    And I get my
    quantity of chocolate
  • 1:38 - 1:42
    is equal to 20 minus 2
    times my quantity of fruit.
  • 1:42 - 1:45
    And I get this budget
    line right over there.
  • 1:45 - 1:47
    We've also looked at the idea
    of an indifference curve.
  • 1:47 - 1:49
    So for example,
    let's say I'm sitting
  • 1:49 - 1:51
    at some point on my
    budget line where
  • 1:51 - 1:55
    I have-- let's say I am
    consuming 18 bars of chocolate
  • 1:55 - 1:57
    and 1 pound of fruit.
  • 1:57 - 1:59
    18-- and you can
    verify that make sense,
  • 1:59 - 2:01
    it's going to be $18
    plus $2, which is $20.
  • 2:01 - 2:05
    So let's say I'm at this
    point on my budget line.
  • 2:05 - 2:09
    18 bars of chocolate,
    so this is in bars,
  • 2:09 - 2:11
    and 1 pound of fruit per month.
  • 2:11 - 2:12
    So that is 1.
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    And this is in pounds.
  • 2:15 - 2:20
    And this is chocolate, and
    this is fruit right over here.
  • 2:20 - 2:22
    Well, we know we have this
    idea of an indifference curve.
  • 2:22 - 2:24
    There's different combinations
    of chocolate and fruit
  • 2:24 - 2:26
    to which we are
    indifferent, to which
  • 2:26 - 2:29
    we would get the same
    exact total utility.
  • 2:29 - 2:31
    And so we can plot
    all of those points.
  • 2:31 - 2:32
    I'll do it in white.
  • 2:32 - 2:33
    It could look
    something like this.
  • 2:33 - 2:36
    I'll do it as a dotted line, it
    makes it a little bit easier.
  • 2:36 - 2:38
    So let me draw it like this.
  • 2:38 - 2:41
    So let's say I'm
    indifferent between any
  • 2:41 - 2:44
    of these points, any of those
    points right over there.
  • 2:44 - 2:46
    Let me draw it a
    little bit better.
  • 2:46 - 2:50
    So between any of these
    points right over there.
  • 2:50 - 2:53
    So for example, I could
    have 18 bars of chocolate
  • 2:53 - 2:58
    and 1 pound of fruit,
    or I could have--
  • 2:58 - 3:00
    let's say that is
    4 bars of chocolate
  • 3:00 - 3:06
    and roughly 8 pounds of fruit.
  • 3:06 - 3:07
    I'm indifferent.
  • 3:07 - 3:10
    I get the same
    exact total utility.
  • 3:10 - 3:12
    Now, am I maximizing
    my total utility
  • 3:12 - 3:14
    at either of those points?
  • 3:14 - 3:16
    Well, we've already
    seen that anything
  • 3:16 - 3:18
    to the top right
    of our indifference
  • 3:18 - 3:21
    curve of this white curve right
    over here-- let me label this.
  • 3:21 - 3:24
    This is our indifference curve.
  • 3:24 - 3:26
    Everything to the top right
    of our indifference curve
  • 3:26 - 3:27
    is preferable.
  • 3:27 - 3:29
    We're going to get
    more total utility.
  • 3:29 - 3:31
    So let me color that in.
  • 3:31 - 3:35
    So everything to the top right
    of our indifference curve
  • 3:35 - 3:36
    is going to be preferable.
  • 3:36 - 3:38
    So all of these other
    points on our budget
  • 3:38 - 3:40
    line, even a few points
    below or budget line,
  • 3:40 - 3:43
    where we would actually
    save money, are preferable.
  • 3:43 - 3:46
    So either of these
    points are not
  • 3:46 - 3:48
    going to maximize
    our total utility.
  • 3:48 - 3:50
    We can maximize or total utility
    at all of these other points
  • 3:50 - 3:53
    in between, along
    our budget line.
  • 3:53 - 3:55
    So to actually maximize
    our total utility
  • 3:55 - 3:58
    what we want to do is find
    a point on our budget line
  • 3:58 - 4:04
    that is just tangent, that
    exactly touches at exactly one
  • 4:04 - 4:06
    point one of our
    indifference curves.
  • 4:06 - 4:08
    We could have an infinite
    number of indifference curves.
  • 4:08 - 4:09
    There could be another
    indifference curve
  • 4:09 - 4:10
    that looks like that.
  • 4:10 - 4:10
    There could be another
    indifferent curve
  • 4:10 - 4:12
    that looks like that.
  • 4:12 - 4:14
    All that says is that we are
    indifferent between any points
  • 4:14 - 4:15
    on this curve.
  • 4:15 - 4:18
    And so there is an indifference
    curve that touches exactly
  • 4:18 - 4:22
    this budget line, or exactly
    touches the line at one point.
  • 4:22 - 4:24
    And so I might have
    an indifference curve
  • 4:24 - 4:26
    that looks like this.
  • 4:26 - 4:29
    Let me do this in a
    vibrant color, in magenta.
  • 4:29 - 4:33
    So I could have an indifference
    curve that looks like this.
  • 4:33 - 4:36
    And because it's tangent, it
    touches at exactly one point.
  • 4:36 - 4:38
    And also the slope of
    my indifference curve,
  • 4:38 - 4:40
    which we've learned
    was the marginal rate
  • 4:40 - 4:46
    of substitution, is the exact
    same as the slope of our budget
  • 4:46 - 4:47
    line right over there,
    which we learned
  • 4:47 - 4:49
    earlier was the relative price.
  • 4:49 - 4:54
    So this right about here
    is the optimal allocation
  • 4:54 - 4:56
    on our budget line.
  • 4:56 - 4:57
    That right here is optimal.
  • 4:57 - 4:59
    And how do we know
    it is optimal?
  • 4:59 - 5:02
    Well, there is no other
    point on the budget line
  • 5:02 - 5:03
    that is to the top right.
  • 5:03 - 5:07
    In fact, every other
    point on our budget line
  • 5:07 - 5:10
    is to the bottom left of
    this indifference curve.
  • 5:10 - 5:15
    So every other point on our
    budget line is not preferable.
  • 5:15 - 5:19
    So remember, everything
    below an indifference curve--
  • 5:19 - 5:20
    so all of this shaded area.
  • 5:20 - 5:21
    Let me actually do
    it in another color.
  • 5:21 - 5:23
    Because indifference
    curve, we are different.
  • 5:23 - 5:25
    But everything below an
    indifference curve, so all
  • 5:25 - 5:29
    of this area in green,
    is not preferable.
  • 5:29 - 5:31
    And every other point
    on the budget line
  • 5:31 - 5:35
    is not preferable to that
    point right over there.
  • 5:35 - 5:38
    Because that's the only point--
    or I guess you could say,
  • 5:38 - 5:39
    every other point
    on our budget line
  • 5:39 - 5:43
    is not preferable to the points
    on the indifference curve.
  • 5:43 - 5:46
    So they're also not preferable
    to that point right over there
  • 5:46 - 5:50
    which actually is on
    the indifference curve.
  • 5:50 - 5:52
    Now, let's think
    about what happens.
  • 5:52 - 5:55
    Let's think about what
    happens if the price of fruit
  • 5:55 - 5:56
    were to go down.
  • 5:56 - 6:05
    So the price of fruit were to
    go from $2 to $1 per pound.
  • 6:05 - 6:08
    So if the price of fruit
    went from $2 to $1, then
  • 6:08 - 6:10
    our actual budget line
    will look different.
  • 6:10 - 6:11
    Our new budget line.
  • 6:11 - 6:13
    I'll do it in blue,
    would look like this.
  • 6:13 - 6:14
    If we spent all our
    money on chocolate,
  • 6:14 - 6:15
    we could buy 20 bars.
  • 6:15 - 6:18
    If we spent all of our money
    on fruit at the new price,
  • 6:18 - 6:20
    we could buy 20 pounds of fruit.
  • 6:20 - 6:25
    So our new budget line would
    look something like that.
  • 6:28 - 6:30
    So that is our new budget line.
  • 6:36 - 6:38
    So now what would be
    the optimal allocation
  • 6:38 - 6:41
    of our dollars or the best
    combination that we would buy?
  • 6:41 - 6:43
    Well, we would do the
    exact same exercise.
  • 6:43 - 6:46
    We would, assuming
    that we had data
  • 6:46 - 6:48
    on all of these
    indifference curves,
  • 6:48 - 6:50
    we would find the
    indifference curve that
  • 6:50 - 6:54
    is exactly tangent to
    our new budget line.
  • 6:54 - 6:57
    So let's say that this
    point right over here
  • 6:57 - 7:01
    is exactly tangent to
    another indifference curve.
  • 7:01 - 7:02
    So just like that.
  • 7:02 - 7:05
    So there's another indifference
    curve that looks like that.
  • 7:05 - 7:07
    Let me draw it a
    little bit neater.
  • 7:07 - 7:11
    So it looks something like that.
  • 7:11 - 7:14
    And so based on how the price--
    if we assume we have access
  • 7:14 - 7:17
    to these many, many, many,
    many, many indifference curves,
  • 7:17 - 7:21
    we can now see based
    on, all else equal,
  • 7:21 - 7:24
    how a change in
    the price of fruit
  • 7:24 - 7:27
    changed the quantity
    of fruit we demanded.
  • 7:27 - 7:30
    Because now our optimal spent
    is this point on our new budget
  • 7:30 - 7:35
    line which looks like it's
    about, well, give or take,
  • 7:35 - 7:37
    about 10 pounds of fruit.
  • 7:37 - 7:40
    So all of a sudden,
    when we were-- so let's
  • 7:40 - 7:41
    think about just the fruit.
  • 7:41 - 7:43
    Everything else
    we're holding equal.
  • 7:43 - 7:47
    So just the fruit, let's
    do, when the price was $2,
  • 7:47 - 7:51
    the quantity demanded
    was 8 pounds.
  • 7:51 - 7:53
    And now when the price
    is $1, the quantity
  • 7:53 - 7:54
    demanded is 10 pounds.
  • 7:54 - 7:56
    And so what we're
    actually doing,
  • 7:56 - 7:59
    and once again, we're kind of
    looking at the exact same ideas
  • 7:59 - 8:00
    from different directions.
  • 8:00 - 8:03
    Before we looked at it in terms
    of marginal utility per dollar
  • 8:03 - 8:05
    and we thought about
    how you maximize it.
  • 8:05 - 8:07
    And we were able to
    change the prices
  • 8:07 - 8:10
    and then figure out and derive
    a demand curve from that.
  • 8:10 - 8:12
    Here we're just looking at it
    from a slightly different lens,
  • 8:12 - 8:15
    but they really are
    all of the same ideas.
  • 8:15 - 8:17
    But by-- assuming
    if we had access
  • 8:17 - 8:19
    to a bunch of
    indifference curves,
  • 8:19 - 8:23
    we can see how a change in
    price changes our budget line.
  • 8:23 - 8:26
    And how that would change
    the optimal quantity
  • 8:26 - 8:28
    we would want of
    a given product.
  • 8:28 - 8:30
    So for example, we
    could keep doing this
  • 8:30 - 8:32
    and we could plot
    our new demand curve.
  • 8:32 - 8:34
    So I could do a demand
    curve now for fruit.
  • 8:34 - 8:37
    At least I have two points
    on that demand curve.
  • 8:37 - 8:39
    So if this is the
    price of fruit and this
  • 8:39 - 8:43
    is the quantity demanded of
    fruit, when the price is $2,
  • 8:43 - 8:44
    the quantity demanded is 8.
  • 8:48 - 8:49
    And when the price
    is-- actually,
  • 8:49 - 8:51
    let me do it a
    little bit different.
  • 8:51 - 8:54
    When the price is $2--
    these aren't to scale--
  • 8:54 - 8:57
    the quantity demanded is 8.
  • 8:57 - 8:59
    Actually let me
    do it here-- is 8.
  • 8:59 - 9:00
    And these aren't to scale.
  • 9:00 - 9:04
    But when the price is $1,
    the quantity demanded is 10.
  • 9:04 - 9:07
    So $2, 8, the quantity
    demanded is 10.
  • 9:09 - 9:12
    And so our demand curve,
    these are two points on it.
  • 9:12 - 9:14
    But we could keep changing
    it up assuming we had access
  • 9:14 - 9:16
    to a bunch of
    indifference curves.
  • 9:16 - 9:18
    We could keep changing
    it up and eventually plot
  • 9:18 - 9:24
    our demand curve, that might
    look something like that.
Title:
Optimal point on budget line | Microeconomics | Khan Academy
Description:

Using indifference curves to think about the point on the budget line that maximizes total utility

Watch the next lesson: https://www.khanacademy.org/economics-finance-domain/microeconomics/choices-opp-cost-tutorial/marginal-utility-tutorial/v/types-of-indifference-curves?utm_source=YT&utm_medium=Desc&utm_campaign=microeconomics

Missed the previous lesson? https://www.khanacademy.org/economics-finance-domain/microeconomics/choices-opp-cost-tutorial/marginal-utility-tutorial/v/indifference-curves-and-marginal-rate-of-substitution?utm_source=YT&utm_medium=Desc&utm_campaign=microeconomics

Microeconomics on Khan Academy: Topics covered in a traditional college level introductory microeconomics course

About Khan Academy: Khan Academy offers practice exercises, instructional videos, and a personalized learning dashboard that empower learners to study at their own pace in and outside of the classroom. We tackle math, science, computer programming, history, art history, economics, and more. Our math missions guide learners from kindergarten to calculus using state-of-the-art, adaptive technology that identifies strengths and learning gaps. We've also partnered with institutions like NASA, The Museum of Modern Art, The California Academy of Sciences, and MIT to offer specialized content.

For free. For everyone. Forever. #YouCanLearnAnything

Subscribe to Khan Academy's Microeconomics channel: https://www.youtube.com/channel/UC_6zQ54DjQJdLodwsxAsdZg
Subscribe to Khan Academy: https://www.youtube.com/subscription_center?add_user=khanacademy

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Khan Academy
Duration:
09:24

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions